Piero Sraffa
Intellectuals & Academics

Piero Sraffa Net Worth


Piero Sraffa is a member of Intellectuals & Academics

Age, Biography and Wiki

Who is it? Founder of the Neo-Ricardian School of Economics
Birth Day August 05, 1898
Birth Place Turin, Italy, Italian
Age 121 YEARS OLD
Died On 3 September 1983(1983-09-03) (aged 85)\nCambridge, England, United Kingdom
Birth Sign Virgo
Field Political economy
School or tradition Neo-Ricardian school
Alma mater London School of Economics
Influences David Ricardo Luigi Einaudi

💰 Net worth

Piero Sraffa, renowned as the Founder of the Neo-Ricardian School of Economics in Italy, is projected to have a net worth ranging from $100K to $1M by the year 2024. Sraffa's contributions to the field of economics have been substantial, particularly in his revitalization of the classical economic theories of David Ricardo. His meticulous research and writings have garnered significant recognition and influence within the academic community. As a result, his net worth is expected to reflect his esteemed standing in the field, with his intellectual endeavors continuing to shape the economic discourse for years to come.

Famous Quotes:

Wittgenstein was insisting that a proposition and that which it describes must have the same 'logical form', the same 'logical multiplicity'. Sraffa made a gesture, familiar to Neapolitans as meaning something like disgust or contempt, of brushing the underneath of his chin with an outward sweep of the finger-tips of one hand. And he asked: 'What is the logical form of that?'

Biography/Timeline

1865

Sraffa was born in Turin, Italy, to Angelo Sraffa (1865–1937) and Irma Sraffa (née Tivoli) (1873–1949) a wealthy Italian Jewish couple. His father was a professor in commercial law and later dean at the Bocconi University in Milan. Despite being raised a practicing Jew, Sraffa later became an agnostic. He studied in his home town and graduated at the local university with a work on inflation in Italy during and after World War I. His tutor was Luigi Einaudi, one of the most important Italian economists and later a President of the Italian Republic.

1921

From 1921 to 1922 he studied at the London School of Economics. In 1922, he was appointed Director of the provincial labour department in Milan, then professor in political economy first in Perugia and later in Cagliari, Sardinia. In Turin he met Antonio Gramsci (the most important leader of Italian Communist Party). They became close friends, partly due to their shared political views. Sraffa was also in contact with Filippo Turati, perhaps the most important leader of the Italian Socialist Party, whom he allegedly met and frequently visited in Rapallo, where his family had a holiday villa.

1925

In 1925, he wrote about returns to scale and perfect competition, underlining some doubtful points of Alfred Marshall's theory of the firm. This was amended for British readers and published in 1926 as The Laws of Returns under Competitive Conditions.

1927

In 1927, Sraffa's yet undiscussed theory of value—but also his friendship with Antonio Gramsci, a risky and compromising endeavor in the context of the Italian fascist regime, considering Gramsci had previously been imprisoned (Sraffa supplied the material, literally pens and paper, with which Gramsci would write his Prison Notebooks)—brought John Maynard Keynes to prudently invite Sraffa to the University of Cambridge, where the Italian Economist was initially assigned a lectureship.

1937

Sraffa was a close friend of Italian Marxist thinker Antonio Gramsci and was instrumental in securing Gramsci's prison notebooks from the Fascist authorities after the latter's death in 1937. Titled “Problems of today and of Tomorrow” Gramsci published 1924 a letter from Sraffa (without signing, signed S.). In the letter Sraffa emphasizes the function of bourgeois opposition in the struggle against fascism and the importance of democratic institutions for the social and political development of the proletariat. Seeing the Communist Party as weak, Sraffa recommended collaboration with the bourgeois opposition to fascism. In his answer Gramsci rejects this suggestion but followed Sraffa’s advice several years later.

1946

In the introduction to Philosophical Investigations, Wittgenstein mentions discussions with Sraffa over many years and says: "I am indebted to this stimulus for the most consequential ideas in this book". In 1946, however, Sraffa broke off his weekly conversations with Wittgenstein over the latter's protests; and when the Philosopher said he would talk about anything Sraffa wanted, "'Yes', Sraffa replied, 'but in your way'".

1960

Nonetheless, Sraffa's work, particularly his interpretation of Ricardo and his Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities (1960), is seen as the starting point of the Neo-Ricardian school in the 1960s. His approach has been described as serving "to help judge Ricardo's Editor and to Illuminate the unity in [his] scientific vision, from before 1926 until death in 1983."

1961

In 1961, when the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel had not yet been created, he was awarded the Söderströmska Gold Medal by the Swedish Academy. In 1972, he was awarded an honorary doctorate by Sorbonne, and in 1976 he received another one from Madrid's Complutense university.

2013

Sraffa was described as a shy and very intelligent man who was devoted to study and books. His library contained more than 8,000 volumes, many of which are now in the Trinity College Library. A popular anecdote claims that Sraffa made successful long-term Investments in Japanese government bonds that he bought the day after the nuclear bombing on Hiroshima and Nagasaki. Another version of this is that Sraffa bought the bonds during the war, when they were trading at distressed prices, as he was convinced that Japan would honour its obligations (Nicholas Kaldor, pp. 66–67).

2014

Sraffa and Wittgenstein influenced each other deeply. They continually corresponded and discussed each other in their journals and notebooks. Both authors were dealing with a form of positivism dominant in their respective disciplines, economics and philosophy. While Wittgenstein made his famous turn from the Tractatus Logico-Philosophicus to the Philosophical Investigations wherein he jettisoned the previous idea that the world comprised an atomistic set of propositional facts for the notion that meaning derives from its use within a holistic self-enclosed system. Analogously, Sraffa was rebutting the Neoclassical paradigm which was similarly atomistic, individualistic and derivational (see Criticisms of neoclassical economics). While there are disputes about how to interpret Sraffa—falling primarily into the neo-classical camp of Paul Samuelson and the Neo-Ricardian of Pierangelo Garegnani—none dispute Sraffa's influence and it can be argued that Sraffa's critique of neo-classical economics is analogous to that of Wittgenstein's of philosophy, in that Sraffa sought to replace the individualistic and positivistic account of price as the result of an equilibration of supply and demand, for instead as price serving a social function, namely to reproduce a stationary or expanding economy given a distribution of income.

Some Piero Sraffa images

About the author

Lisa Scholfield

As a Senior Writer at Famous Net Worth, I spearhead an exceptional team dedicated to uncovering and sharing the stories of pioneering individuals. My passion for unearthing untold narratives drives me to delve deep into the essence of each subject, bringing forth a unique blend of factual accuracy and narrative allure. In orchestrating the editorial workflow, I am deeply involved in every step—from initial research to the final touches of publishing, ensuring each biography not only informs but also engages and inspires our readership.